Metarepresented Money

Keeping Ownership Decentralized

Money represents a future commodity ownership. However, the only way of keeping this ownership rightful, hence decentralized, is to price commodities in metarepresented money. Any otherwise priced future ownership will not remain rightfully decentralized.

Still, what is metarepresented money?

Direct Commodity Exchange

Let there be two owners A and B of commodities x and y, respectively, of whom A wants y and B wants x. Without any money — whether metarepresented or not — the only way for bitcoin blackjack both people to obtain their desired commodities is directly from each other:

 

A --> y | B --> x

x _____ | y

y _____ | x

 

Otherwise, A and B must delegate their commodity ownership to someone who then redistributes it between them. However, such a centralized solution would at least partially contradict the same ownership, by at least partially taking it away from its rightful controllers. Hence, only a decentralized solution can preserve all commodity ownership legitimizing this exchange, by A and B exchanging x and y directly.

Individual Multiequivalence

Still, direct commodity exchange poses two problems:

 

  1. Let there be now (as follows) three owners AB, and C of one unit of commodity x, one of y, and two units of y, respectively. Additionally, let A want the most units of y, while B and C want at least one of x each. Then, the available unit of x will be worth one and a half units of y. So either A loses value to B or C to A — since the exchangeable quantities of x and y are not worth the same:
    A --> y | B --> x | C --> x
    x(1.5y) | y _____ | 2y
    
  2. Let (as follows) AB, and C own a single unit respectively of xy, and z. Additionally, let A want yB want z, and C want x. Then, direct exchange could not give any of those three owners their desired commodity — as none of them has the same commodity wanted by who owns their wanted one. Moneyless exchange now can only happen if one of their commodities becomes a simultaneous equivalent of the other two, at least for whom neither wants nor has it. So it becomes a multiequivalent, whether the other two owners also know of that multiequivalence or not. For example, A could give x in exchange for z just to then give z for y, this way making z a multiequivalent (as asterisked):
    A --> y | B --> z | C --> x
    x _____ | y _____ | z*
    z* ____ | y _____ | x
    y _____ | z _____ | x
    

 

Likewise, this individually handled multiequivalence poses a new pair of problems:

 

  1. It allows for conflicting indirect exchanges. In the same example, any two or even all three owners could simultaneously try to handle it. For instance, while A would give x in exchange for z (then z for y), B could rather try to give y for the same x (then x for z). To avoid this conflict, AB, and C must delegate now their individual choice of handling multiequivalence to a public authority — whether to their consensual one or even to other people’s. However, such a centralized solution would again at least partially contradict their commodity ownership, by at least partially taking it away from them.
  2. In addition to allowing the exchangeable quantities of two commodities not to be equivalent, its indirectness increases the likelihood of that mismatch, by requiring additional direct exchanges. Let the same owners AB, and C of a single unit respectively of xy, and z want the most units respectively of yz, and x. Additionally, let a fourth owner D of two units of z want at least one of x. Then, the available units of x and y will each be worth one and a half units of z. Finally, again let z be an individual multiequivalent. Now, either A loses value to C or D to A, then respectively B to A and A to B — since the exchangeable quantities of xy, and z are not worth the same.

 

Social Multiequivalence (Money)

Fortunately, all those problems have the same and only resolution of a single multiequivalent m becoming social, or money. Then, commodity owners can either give (sell) their commodities in exchange for m or give m for (buy) the commodities they want. For example, again let AB, and C own commodities xy, and z, respectively. Still assuming A wants yB wants z, and C wants x, if now they only exchange their commodities for that m social multiequivalent — initially owned just by A — then:

 

A --> y | B --> z | C --> x

x, m __ | y _____ | z

x, y __ | m _____ | z

x, y __ | z _____ | m

y, m __ | z _____ | x

 

With social (rather than individual) multiequivalence:

 

  1. There are only two exchanges (either a buy or a sell) for each commodity, regardless of who owns or wants which commodities.
  2. All commodity owners exchange a common (social) multiequivalent, which eventually returns to its original owner.

 

Finally, with a social multiequivalent (money) divisible into small and similar enough units, any two commodities can always be equivalent, even if their exchangeable quantities are not. For example, let commodities x and y be worth three and two units of a social multiequivalent m, respectively — x(3m) and y(2m). Then, let their owners A of x and B of y be also the owners respectively of two and three units of that money — A of 2m and B of 3m. If A and B want y and x, respectively, but only exchange their commodities for m units — x for 3m and y for 2m — then:

 

A --> y _ | B --> x

x(3m), 2m | y(2m), 3m

y(2m), 3m | x(3m), 2m

 

Privately Concrete Money

So money must always represent a future commodity ownership. Otherwise, people’s money could not always represent their future ownership of anything it can buy. Additionally, to exchange their money, these people must share it with any of those with whom they exchange it. Indeed, people’s exchanged money must represent their future commodity ownership to all of them, even though of different commodities as either buyers or sellers. However, despite purchased by the same exchanged money, this future ownership remains exclusive to either group, which hence cannot share it with the other one. Then, how can the two still share its representation between them?

How could money be simultaneously shareable as that which represents a future ownership and not shareable as each future ownership it represents?

Is all money only shareable instead of also not shareable, by only representing an indefinite future ownership instead of also a definite one? Yet how could money only buy unspecified commodities? It cannot, since people cannot buy anything without specifying their future ownership of it as represented by their money to the seller.

 

Keeping Ownership Decentralized Money represents a future commodity ownership. However, the only way of keeping this ownership rightful, hence decentralized, is to price commodities in metarepresented money. Any otherwise priced future ownership will not remain rightfully decentralized. Still, what is metarepresented money? Direct Commodity Exchange Let there be two owners A and B of commodities x and y, respectively, of whom A wants y and B wants x. Without…

Keeping Ownership Decentralized Money represents a future commodity ownership. However, the only way of keeping this ownership rightful, hence decentralized, is to price commodities in metarepresented money. Any otherwise priced future ownership will not remain rightfully decentralized. Still, what is metarepresented money? Direct Commodity Exchange Let there be two owners A and B of commodities x and y, respectively, of whom A wants y and B wants x. Without…

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.